<< All Episodes

Episode 136 – Money and the Limits of Sovereignty with Scott Ferguson

Episode 136 - Money and the Limits of Sovereignty with Scott Ferguson

FOLLOW THE SHOW

What happens if we rid ourselves of the semantic baggage of monetary “sovereignty”? Scott Ferguson, co-host of Money on the Left podcast, has some thoughts.

Scott Ferguson serves as editor of the Money on the Left (MotL) Editorial Collective and co-host of the Money on the Left podcast. In July, he was guest speaker at Real Progressives’ event, RP Live. This week, Macro N Cheese is presenting his talk, Money and the Limits of Sovereignty, in its entirety, along with most of the Q&A discussion. 

Trying to summarize the presentation would be doing it a disservice. The idea of sovereignty is one that has been a point of discussion – and a certain amount of controversy – among the MMT community for some time. The work of MotL has contributed enormously to expanding our understanding and considering it in a new, multi-faceted light.  

Scott begins with the semantic history of the term “sovereignty” and its use in 14th or 15th century Europe to introduce a new conception of political rule, though not always with consistency. It has been used to justify political philosophy on both the left and right.  

Yet fundamentally, for us, the logic of sovereignty is violent because it denies that everything in this world is interdependent—which is to say, meaningfully and necessarily intertwined–in both social and ecological senses.  

Meanwhile, we contend that sovereignty as a concept is false because everything, in our interpretation actually is interdependent, no matter how much the logics or institutions of sovereignty pretend they are not.   

Interdependence opens opportunities for participation and cooperation as well as competition. We could replace “sovereignty” with the language of monetary “capacity,” “power,” and “agency” as well as “sustainability” and “resilience.” 

We tend to equate money with private exchange, revenue-driven relations, and the profit motive. We operate under the specter of privation. MMT teaches us money is not a zero-sum game; scarcity is a social construct. Scott suggests we extend the vision to political and social relations more generally.  

The second half of the episode contains Q&A discussion that followed Scott’s presentation. After listening to the episode, we suggest you read the transcript. The complete text of Scott’s presentation is available on our transcript page and elsewhere on RealProgressives.org.  

Scott Ferguson serves as editor for The Money on the Left Editorial Collective. He is a research scholar at the Global Institute for Sustainability Prosperity and co-host of Money on the Left podcast. Scott holds a Ph.D. in Rhetoric and Film Studies. 

moneyontheleft.org 

@videotroph  

Macro N Cheese – Episode 136
Money and the Limits of Sovereignty with Scott Ferguson
September 4, 2021

 

[00:00:03.550] – Scott Ferguson [intro/music]

Throughout the early modern period, this new word, this new idea of sovereignty would be twisted in various and seemingly conflicting directions. Sovereignty, for instance, has equally underwrote absolutist argument with the divine right of kings or later modern fascism, as well as liberal and leftist ideas about republicanism or socialism.

[00:00:26.230] – Scott Ferguson [intro/music]

Instead of finance franchisees lending money that must be paid back, for example, we can establish granting institutions that disperse credit not according to a logic of quantitative payback, but rather through a qualitative logic of communal and environmental obligation.

[00:01:35.310] – Geoff Ginter [intro/music]

Now let’s see if we can avoid the apocalypse altogether. Here’s another episode of Macro N Cheese with your host, Steve Grumbine.

[00:01:43.170] – Steve Grumbine

And this is Steve with Macro N Cheese. This week we’re bringing you something different. My friend Scott Ferguson is the editor of Money on the Left Editorial Collective and co-host of the Money on the Left podcast. Scott has already been on Macro N Cheese several times. And in July, he was our guest on Real Progressive webinar series RP Live. He gave a presentation on Money and the Limits of Sovereignty, and it was so interesting I wanted to bring this to the Macro N Cheese audience. After his presentation, he took questions from the attendees. Folks, you’re going to love this episode.

[00:02:19.210] – Ferguson

Here we go. So, I’ve titled my remarks today, Money and the Limits of Sovereignty.

As many of you are no doubt aware, my colleagues and I at the Money on the Left (MotL) Editorial Collective have offered some challenges to the notion of sovereignty within MMT scholarship over the last few years. I am grateful for this opportunity to explain and hopefully clarify (a) what we are actually claiming about money and sovereignty; (b) what we are certainly not saying; and (c) why all of this matters, in our view.  

MMT is, as we know, a state-based theory of endogenous credit money creation. This means that, for MMT, money arises from and remains primarily secured by centralized governments and that credit is created as needed as a function of monetary design.

The original MMT literature draws upon the German chartalist scholar Friedrich Knapp, who argued that money is first and foremost a token of the state. 

Where things get tricky, for myself and others in the MotL Collective, is that the modern nation-state has been overwhelmingly defined by the concept of sovereignty.  

Sovereignty, to begin with a preliminary definition, typically denotes a type of power characterized as the highest independent authority within a given territory. 

The most widely used notion of sovereignty is sometimes qualified as “political sovereignty,” referring to an entire political entity in all of its various functions, domains, and concerns.  

From this wider category, MMTers such as L. Randall Wray and Fadhel Kaboub have derived a theory of “monetary sovereignty.”  

Monetary sovereignty, for MMT, is linked to political sovereignty, but forms a specialized category of its own.  

This monetary type of sovereignty speaks, in a sense, to the economic dimensions of state power.  

One might say that monetary sovereignty, in this conception, is a sub-species of political sovereignty that reciprocally helps to shape the political order.  

Kaboub, in particular, has developed a helpful four-point list of criteria for defining monetary sovereignty. A so-called “full” monetary sovereign should include all four criteria. They are: 

(1) a country must issue its own currency  

(2) a country must levy taxes, fines and fees in its own currency  

(3) a country can only issue debt denominated in its own currency  

(4) a country must avoid currency pegs & engage internationally via floating exchange rates  

On the bases of these four criteria, Kaboub and others set forth an admittedly nuanced MMT approach to monetary sovereignty, one that works not in absolutes, but in degrees. 

Although not always evident in popular MMT discourse, deep down MMT does not actually promulgate a crude model of monetary sovereignty at all. MMT does not, for example, stretch monetary sovereignty between the twin extremes of “having” and “not having.” 

Instead, MMTers situate different monetary regimes with what they deem a “spectrum monetary sovereignty.”  

According to this spectrum thinking, countries exhibit a wide variety of different monetary powers with respect to one another.  

No country is all-powerful since there are always political and resource constraints that must be confronted and negotiated.  

Conversely, no country can be totally without monetary capacities because any polity can create new credit regimes in order to freshly mobilize people and resources.

As I understand it, this spectrum approach is no mere quantitative checklist, either. 

At least at its best, it tends to be deployed in qualitative and historically contextualized ways such that, for example, one country may share two of the very same criteria with another but also have very different monetary powers at their disposal.  

Importantly, moreover, MMTers clearly discern that none of these features are natural or inevitable. They are politically and legally constructed over time and can always be challenged and redesigned.   

Indeed, I would maintain that these presumptions about contingency and transformability are precisely what MMTers have in mind when discussing monetary sovereignty, even as their language slips occasionally into logics of having and not having as a shorthand. 

Just because a particular country’s currency, for example, is pegged to the dollar today, according to MMTers, does not then condemn them to monetary powerlessness for eternity.  

That is why MMT’s theory of monetary sovereignty matters.  

This, I hope, is an accurate and judicious account of what MMT has meant by the expression “monetary sovereignty.”  

Now as I’ve stated, my colleagues and I at MotL have criticized the term sovereignty, complicating the role it has played both in MMT literature and in popular outreach.  

This has led some in the MMT community to feel confused and others quite resistant, imagining that what we are saying must somehow undercut MMT and its explanatory power.  

Well, I’m here tonight to not only clear up the confusion surrounding our critique of the concept of sovereignty, but also explain why we think our contribution improves rather than detracts from the MMT project.  

Let me commence by stating at the outset that I come in peace. I’m not here to destroy MMT. I’m honestly here to help. 

In this spirit, the first substantive point I want to make is a meta or methodological one.  

The point is this: Words and the concepts they express have complex histories and any account of sovereignty must attend to the history of the term itself.  

Indeed, words with seemingly stable meanings in one era can often mean something very different in another. Sometimes, a word can mean one thing and its very opposite!  

To take such tangled word histories seriously is not to indulge a type of nihilistic relativism in which we toss our hands in the air and declare that nothing means anything at all! To the contrary, it only means we should be aware of the words we use and their complex semantic legacies. 

This is especially true when it comes to the central and very important words we use to make sense of politics and economics.  

What about the word and idea of “sovereignty,” then?  

Turns out, it, too, has a history.   

Modern writers tacitly deny this all of the timeWhen modern thinkers turn back to ancient Greek, Roman or Christian writers to understand the allegedly antique origins of sovereignty, they retro-actively impose a modern conception of politics onto texts that were in truth never concerned with sovereignty as it is understood in the modern world.  

In actuality, the word sovereignty arose in early modern Europe over the long course of the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries in order to articulate a new conception of political rule.  

Prior to the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, people in the European and wider Mediterranean world referred to political rule most often as a matter of “imperium.”  

Imperium meant, pretty straightforwardly, “rule,” “authority or “command,” framed as a general condition or question.  

Today, when we hear this Latin term “imperium” we are apt to associate it with the nasty modern notion of “empire.” This implies the political and economic domination of vast lands and peoples, employing violent means toward exploitative ends.  

In its historical context, however, imperium did not actually mean empire or territorial domination in that specific and narrowly modern sense.  

In fact, the word rose to prominence within the Roman Republic well before the Empire.   

Imperium in the Roman Republic denoted broadly who, what, how, when and where authority rules. 

Particularly during the Middle Ages, the elasticity of this term proved handy since the period was very self-consciously defined by a dizzying array of overlapping and interdependent jurisdictions. 

While the Holy Roman Empire and Catholic Church oversaw enormous and interpenetrating realms, myriad kingdoms, manors, and townships within these realms formed a nested latticework of interlocking rights and obligations.  

In this period, it is crucial to stress, political rule was seen as a necessary and inescapable part of humanity’s social interdependence, no matter what form it took.  

Leaders and thinkers, too, expressly situated any particular political regime within a larger inter-reliant world of political, social, legal and religious relations, one that of course exceeded any specific ruler or regime.  

The Middle Ages definitely saw its fair share of wars, feuds, and crusades during which different and opposing communities fought over any number of matters pertaining to political rule and legal jurisdiction.  

However, medieval thought did not articulate any of such conflicts in terms of absolute insides and outsides, selves and others.  

Today, we may certainly level plenty of legitimate criticisms at the period’s hierarchal political economy and anti-democratic order of rewards and succession.  

Yet as any medieval historian will frankly tell you, the modern world’s cartoonish depictions of unquestioned authoritarianism during the Middle Ages simply hold no water. 

The medieval period did, in fact, witness plenty of political contestation, both in word and in deed.  

The period’s leaders and thinkers developed a keen sense for what constituted the legitimacy of rule. 

They appreciated the limits of authority.

Tyranny, too, was a concern, and was variously criticized and resisted.  

In late medieval and early modern Europe, however, various jurists, theologians and philosophers began to invent a new and quite unfamiliar idea of political rule, which broke severely with previous conceptions.  

To get at this historically novel idea, it is instructive to return to and inspect the word “sovereignty” itself.  

This word sovereignty combines the term “reign,” meaning “rule,” with a superlative prefix related to modern prefixes with which we are now familiar like “super” or “hyper,” meaning at once “above” and “beyond.”  

So, in a very literal sense, the word sovereignty is created to imagine a new kind of super or hyper power meant to rule over and above all others.  

With this, those who conceived sovereignty as an idea sought to reconceive and seemingly disentangle the multifarious and overlapping cascade that was Medieval rule.  

Their desire was to imagine and ground a type of authority that would be self-legitimating and stand outside of these medieval entanglements.  

It would do so in a number of interrelated ways. Here, I’m going to try to spell out eight: 

First, the notion of sovereignty tended to fuse political rule with individual will. That will might belong to particular emperor or king, but it would also be later ascribe to a particular group of people, as in Jean-Jacques Rousseau’s notorious idea of the “general will.”

Second, the concept of sovereignty aligned this notion of willful rule with single site of power, which would then be associated with a very particular and distinctly bounded sense of territory.

Third, sovereignty as a concept demanded the political power would command exclusive authority over said territory, barring all other political actors.  

Fourth, sovereignty as an idea assumed that the political realm is an artificial construct erected through contract and backed by violence, or at least the threat of violence.  

Fifth, it presumed that political & legal institutions are not necessary for organizing relations and mediating conflict between interdependent beings and realms, as was believed in the Middle Ages.  

Instead, the logic of sovereignty began with a so-called “state of nature,” wherein apparently disconnected and naturally independent individuals, families, or organizations come together as matter of choice and, ultimately, force.   

Sixth, the notion of sovereignty tended to subordinate every relationship or organization within a supposedly sovereign territory to an expression of the overarching sovereign will.  

Seventh, sovereignty starkly divided inside from outside sovereign borders.  

That is, it held not only that seemingly external concerns or domains were simply not a matter of sovereign responsibility, but also that the people within a sovereign territory were in no way related or beholden to those outside of it.    

Eighth, whether explicitly or implicitly, sovereignty created a political vacuum between territorial regimes. In opposition to the wildly interwoven jurisdictions of the Middle Ages, this raised constant questions and problems about the order of things in the seemingly external spaces between regimes.  

Perhaps the most well-known mature articulation of the early modern logic of sovereignty came from Thomas Hobbes in his well-known book Leviathan or The Matter, Forme and Power of a Commonwealth Ecclesiasticall and Civil. That book was published in 1651 during the uncertain period of the English Civil War. But in many ways, Hobbes represents the first early culmination of a tradition that includes many earlier works such as those written by French jurist Jean Bodin.  

I cannot offer a thorough or in any way satisfying summary of Hobbes’s or Bodin’s arguments here beyond the admittedly hand-wavy sketch I’ve already provided.   

Suffice it to say that throughout the early modern period, this new word and idea of sovereignty would be twisted in various and seemingly conflicting directions.  

Sovereignty, for instance, has equally underwrote absolutist arguments for the divine right of kings or, later, modern fascism, as well as Liberal and leftist ideas about Republicanism or socialism.  

Eventually, as we know, sovereignty would give rise to the idea and institution known as the modern nation-state.  

The modern nation-states presumes an independent organic or ethnically related community–sometimes conceived as a hybrid or melting pot of several communities.  

In any case, no matter what political form said community takes, the nation-state model imagines government as the expression or representative of that organic community’s independent will.  

Equally important, the modern nation-state presumes a particular global organization of politics, one that is comprised of supposedly independent territories.  

Such sovereign territories, goes this logic, relate to one another as external, regionally specific and ethnically bounded populations.  

Said order of sovereign nation-states is sometimes referred to as the so-called “Westphalian” system after the famous “Treaty” or “Peace of Westphalia.” Constructed out of what were in fact two important treaties in the mid-17th century, the Peace of Westphalia brokered a new order of security between rival powers, closing a calamitous period of European religious warfare that had by that point killed approximately eight million people. 

It is now a truism that the Peace of Westphalia established the order of sovereign nation-states that gave rise to the modern world. 

For a critique of this just so story, I recommend a great article from 2011 by Sebastian Schmidt titled, “To Order the Minds of Scholars: The Discourse of the Peace of Westphalia in International Relations Literature.” You can find it in the journal International Studies Quarterly.  

As Schmidt and other critics have explained, the nation-state as we know it did not arrive overnight after the Peace of Westphalia.  

Nothing even close to its idealized early modern theorization arose as a generalized institutional form until the 19th century.  

Some have even argued that the nation-state as a general form doesn’t fully come into its own until the 20th century when the midcentury era of decolonization saw an explosion of freshly formed nation-states on the model of European sovereignty.  

For my colleagues and I at MotL, the ultimate problem with sovereignty and the modern nation-state system is two-fold.   

Put succinctly, we argue that the logic of sovereignty is not only violent, it is also outright false.    

Sovereignty as a concept is violent for many reasons. Most plainly, it is violent because it presumes that political rule is always founded upon violence or a monopoly on force.  

Yet fundamentally, for us, the logic of sovereignty is violent because it denies that everything in this world is interdependent—which is to say, meaningfully and necessarily intertwined–in both social and ecological senses.  

Meanwhile, we contend that sovereignty as a concept is false because everything, in our interpretation actually is interdependent, no matter how much the logics or institutions of sovereignty pretend they are not.   

The interlinked crises of global climate change are, of course, screaming evidence that autonomy is a myth and interdependence is the actual name of the game.  

But interdependence goes well beyond matters of crisis.  

It also provides at least as many opportunities for cooperation and participation as it does problems and competition.  

In any case, on MotL’s view, sovereignty disastrously fails to describe the reality of global political economy in any helpful way.  

Today, we would add, the world remains, in a sense, thoroughly medieval, by which I mean, that our world, too, remains a dizzying array of overlapping and interdependent jurisdictions, with credit creation occurring across and between different forms and scales.  

The idea of sovereignty does not permit us to actually perceive this, let alone change it for the improvement of humanity and the planet.  

To clarify: When we critique sovereignty as a concept, we are not flatly critiquing analysts, activists or legislators for focusing on the existing countries or governments in the world.  

We are all for politicizing, challenging, and transforming extant countries and governments for the better.  

Thus we do not in any way wish to ignore or overlook American, French, Japanese or Senegalese governments in the name of either a hyper-localist politics or a supranational globalism. 

Nor do we wish to immediately or unequivocally abolish the state.  

To the contrary, we don’t take the modern nation-state at its word about its own alleged sovereignty. Instead, we want to challenge this misconception, while working to radically transform and transcend the nation-state.  

In this way, we continue to argue that MMT’s fundamental insights about political economy are both correct and urgent.  

Our message is that, given its historical legacy and the problems associated with its meanings, sovereignty may not be the best descriptor for us to use when we are trying to understand present political economy and to release what have been historically repressed currency-creating powers.  

As a retort, one could persuasively argue that MMT has thoroughly transformed sovereignty’s original meaning by giving it a new and very specific set of definitions and criteria, none of which necessitate that we treat the modern-nation state as a self-standing and territorially bounded agent. 

To this we say: Fair enough! Our critique, then, may perhaps simply serve as a reminder that sovereignty’s semantic legacy is a problematic one. Maybe what we have to offer is merely a word of caution against perpetuating sovereignty’s unquestioned assumptions.  

But we can and do go further: The semantic baggage of terms like sovereignty has a tricky way of haunting new usages, even as they aim to outstrip their pasts.  

We see this around MMT, for example, when critics who, ignoring the nuances in the literature, conflate MMT with statism, as best, and autarky, at worst. 

It also comes from certain members within the MMT movement, who avowedly embrace MMT for ethno-nationalist politics.  

For this reason, we do recommend phasing out the language of sovereignty in order to avoid these problematic associations.  

Instead, we prefer to use the language of monetary “capacity,” “power,” “capability,” “agency,” or in some circumstances, “sustainability” and “resilience.”  

These terms, we think, better and more accurately describe what MMT is getting at in the first place.  

The largely unquestioned implications of sovereignty, we would also suggest, can hamper MMT from time to time, bogging us down in unnecessary contradictions.  

On one hand, for example, MMT stresses that money is an endogenous credit/debt relation, as opposed to, say, a finite thing, or a passive vehicle for individual preferences or an expression of commodified labor time.  

Money on this view is never recycled like a finite chit or embodiment of value. It is created from thin air by virtue of credit granting institutions endowed with different degrees of authority and receivability.  

On the other hand, however, MMT tells us that only sovereign currency-issuing governments have the power to create credit, while everyone else is condemned to be a mere user of credit that must recycle extant money throughout the economy.  

Such statements contradict one another.  

Which one is it? Is credit created from thin air through a hierarchy of money that extends in endogenous patterns from government to locality and across the globe?  

Or, is the government’s sovereign will the sole locus of infinite money creation, while every other person, group or institution must merely use and recycle said money as if it were a finite substance?  

The problem, here, I would wager is not that MMT is deep down just bluntly wrong or self-undermining.  

It is not wrong to emphasize the important and central role played by federal governments in organizing money.  

MMT does not undermine itself by explaining the hierarchy of endogenous monetary creation. 

The trouble is in tethering government’s role in the process to language and assumptions of sovereignty, permitting sovereignty’s absolutist and exclusionary logics to creep back in.  

This is what creates these puzzling and, frankly, needless contradictions in MMT.   

In truth, I would suggest that MMT scholars know damn well and express all of the time that state money and endogenous money are not in conflict.  

MMT scholars know that credit issuance occurs in heterogenous forms across global and local registers.  

While government currency issuers variously anchor these forms, we see myriad regimes of non-finite, non-recycled credit all of the time—from IMF Special Drawing Rights and Euro dollars to airline miles and Chuck E. Cheese tickets.  

The modern nation-state unquestionably plays important roles in authorizing, regulating and even informally sanctioning credit creation across these heterogeneous scales. And the nation-state is arguably the central institution with which we should now be concerned.  

But to take the nation-state seriously does not then mean that we must blind ourselves by naturalizing the fantasies of absolute independence and exclusivity baked into sovereignty as a historical term and concept.  

This matters not only for describing the current monetary systems of the world, but also for imaginatively transforming money into a more robust and democratic process.  

A great example of this is the proposal my colleagues and I have been developing for a public university issued credit system we call “the Uni.” 

The Uni, as we conceive it, would give credit creation capacity to cash-strapped public universities, which have been increasingly starved of funds by feckless state legislatures for decades. 

Extending what Hockett and Omarova call the “finance franchise” to public universities, the Uni would end austerity and privatization in public universities. It would also, on our design, increase the democratic agency of faculty, staff, students, and surrounding community members.

Perhaps the most mind-blowing aspect of the Uni, furthermore, is what it demonstrates about the plasticity of endogenous credit creation.

The Uni shows that no one is merely a passive user of a currency, that credit always precedes return and that, as a result, money as such is never driven by recycling revenue.  

This has tremendous implications for democratic monetary design, challenging us to imagine credit systems that transcend not only revenue constraints but also the profit motive.  

Instead of finance franchisees lending money that must be paid back, for example, we can establish granting institutions that disburse credit not according to a logic of quantitative payback but, rather, through a qualitative logic of communal and environmental obligation.

Crucially, we think, the Uni can serve as a generalizable model for similar projects elsewhere, revealing MMT’s still-untapped potentials for political and economic transformation in unexpected ways.

From one point of view, the Uni is fully compatible with and wholly stems from MMT.  

At the same time, however, we believe that the language and logics of state sovereignty that linger in MMT sometimes have a tendency to squelch such imaginative leaps and possibilities.  

Now, I’d like to quickly sum up before concluding:  

  1. I come in peace, which is to say, I’ve spoken with you here tonight in order to improve rather than to condemn MMT. 
  2. MMT’s spectrum of monetary sovereignty is important and persuasive on its own terms.
  3. Sovereignty is neither an innocent nor ahistorical synonym for the power of the federal government. 
  4. Sovereignty arose as a very specific term and concept, which sought to expel interdependence from political thinking and organization. 
  5. The logic of sovereignty is not only violent, but also false.
  6. We can and should appeal to alternative words to describe the world of monetary governance such as monetary “agency,” “power,” “capacity,” and others.
  7. Moving beyond sovereignty enables us to expand MMT and iron out some unfortunate limits and contradictions in MMT discourse.

Thank you again for inviting me to share our work at the Money on the Left collective. I am honored to have had this chance to walk you through our thinking and concerns. 

[00:32:04.790] – Intermission

You are listening to Macro N Cheese, a podcast brought to you by Real Progressives, a non-profit organization dedicated to teaching the masses about MMT or Modern Monetary Theory. Please help our efforts and become a monthly donor at PayPal or Patreon, like and follow our pages on Facebook and YouTube, and follow us on Periscope, Twitter, and Instagram.

[00:33:00.960] – Grumbine

All right, question one. Now I’m going to read the questions from the audience. We’re starting with a passage from the Money on the Left interview with Professor Lua Yuille. She was talking about her early exposure to MMT. When I started having these conversations, there was precious little view of how we should have these MMT conversations.

And what does Modern Monetary Theory mean for the developing world? Or what are you supposed to do with these great insights if your country isn’t a monetary sovereign? That is even more frustrating and problematic when the voices that are telling you these things are overwhelmingly white and notwithstanding the huge female luminaries in the MMT space, they’re really male.

A few minutes later, Professor Yuille said, I think that is a real challenge both in the presentation and a challenge of sometimes the utopian flavor of how we talk about things. Because, again, if you go into places where there’s a lot of black people, power has never been our friend. Power has never worked for us. So when you tell us all about the possibility of power, I’m not exactly or necessarily sure that’s making me excited.

[00:34:15.100] – Ferguson

Okay, so there’s a lot going on there. I love Lua. I love her work and how multifaceted it is. I think we share a commitment to beginning with interdependence. That’s very important for the way she thinks about property, race, and law in addition to money and its role.

And what I would say is, I think a lot of people in this particular event, in this particular audience probably have maybe more of a sense of the work of Fadhel Kaboub and Ndongo Symba Sylla and others who have been thinking about the so-called Global South and MMT – explanatory and political power in those places.

To say that that hasn’t been the most vocal part of MMT popularization is fair and that more work needs to be done. I think I share Lua’s concern and also have plenty of literature to point her and others in the direction of. I think specifically when we’re talking about historically repressed groups and racialized groups such as black people and other people of color.

I, of course, agree and totally understand why people from that community would be suspicious of a bunch of white people and especially white men, seemingly naively glorifying the power of money to change the world when those communities have not been able to trust those in power for years and years and years. That said, what I think I am committed to, and I think a lot of us in the MMT community are committed to is precisely empowering.

And I don’t want people of color to think of themselves as mere money users, mere recyclers of finite dollars that the center of power can infinitely produce. But sorry, I’m not going to produce it for you. So you have to simply recycle. I want them to think of themselves. And here I really draw a lot of learning and inspiration from my friend and colleague Jakob Feinig, who we’ve interviewed on Money to the Left.

You can find that interview at Monthly Review online or on our website. They should think of themselves as agents who are participating in money systems. And this is not to deny that they have been rendered relatively powerless, but it is to say that there are ways of organizing and ways of conceiving of that organizing and making certain demands.

And I’m not here to police people on how they want to organize, whether they want to march or stage boycotts or do direct actions that are more physically involved. It takes all kinds in all kinds of ways to mount resistance. But if we don’t start from the point of view that we are all participants in money and money isn’t necessarily a finite recycling game and open up our imagination not to just we can afford a job guarantee.

But I’ve spoken with some of the leaders of the Black Lives movement in Tampa, and I was trying to talk to them about MMT and about endogenous money creation, and they were talking about creating a community garden and then maybe establishing a public bank connected to it. And I was trying to suggest to them that this is about securing the finance franchise.

It’s about securing and empowering yourself to be able to issue credit in your community. Right. Not just borrow and lend and accumulate capital. That stuff is important for marginalized communities, but you need to be empowered to see a path to your own empowerment. And that means really seeing clearly how endogenous money really works. So that’s my wandering response to those quotations.

[00:38:16.800] – Grumbine

What are your thoughts on El Salvador a country without monetary independence? They use the US dollar as their currency and have now taken on Bitcoin as a secondary currency.

[00:38:29.520] – Ferguson

I would just follow Fadhel Kaboub, right? And suggest that they can create a credit system, and they would need to do so carefully, and they would have to roll it out in a carefully sequenced plan. Right. And they might have to limit the degrees of receivability like in terms of what you can purchase.

But Fadhel Kaboub’s argument is you issue your own endogenous currency, your own endogenous credit, and you do so with directed industrial policy for sustainable energy and agricultural production within your country and build up your monetary capacity that way.

Of course, there’s lots of other things you can do. You can band together with other countries. You can form a currency union. Right. There’s all kinds of options. But I think just in terms of, like what a country can do equipped with MMT, I would just follow Fadhel Kaboub.

[00:39:30.950] – Grumbine

When the US government decided not to bail out the people, was it connected to the elites wanting their US dollar wealth to command a higher exchange rate with those countries that are bailing out their people?

[00:39:44.300] – Ferguson

I guess I would believe that’s in part the case. I think it’s also the old Marxist explanation of elites keeping a reserve army of the unemployed and the disenfranchised at their disposal so that they can push wages down, break unions, and exploit people more at home and abroad.

I guess the one twist on this that I would say is I think MMT encourages us to question the notion that keeping a reserve army of unemployed, keeping recessionary and depressive tendencies in communities and sectors actually increases the value of the currency beyond the FX market  [editor: Foreign Exchange].

The quality of social value of a currency is a function of the system of governance and the system of production. And if it’s creating all kinds of things and services and relationships, then that makes a currency more valuable. Right. So a job guarantee would be more valuable. The idea that somehow more people participating in doing more things through the US dollar because of a job guarantee is going to somehow make the dollar less valuable is, to me, one of the bonkers presuppositions of classical and neoclassical economics and Fed policy and the Phillips Curve and all of this nonsense.

So then back to FX market and maybe the FX market, the traders and the ideology of those markets, they feel confidence. They feel those animal spirits of confidence when the US is bailing out the elite and not bailing out the people, and maybe then they value the US dollar more. But I think that all of that is very twisted in its logic, and maybe the elite are trying to do this for FX leveraging, but I’m not even sure it works the way they say it does.

[00:41:58.440] – Grumbine

Could national monetary independence be a term to replace monetary sovereignty?

[00:42:04.260] – Ferguson

The reason why I prefer agency or capacity is because agency and capacity can be thought of as being part of an interdependent system. And one of the things that we at The Money on the Left Collective really try to hammer home is MMT teaches us more narrowly that money is not a zero-sum game, and our point is to extend that to basically reality and political and social relations more generally.

So we think it’s better to speak in terms of what lots of agents can do in global, national, and local, national, and international context in ways that don’t fetishize freedom or autonomy. Right. So it’s not that we’re saying people shouldn’t be able to actualize their Democratic agency and participation and have a say in what they make and the way things are organized we want that. But we also think that essentially sovereignty is a synonym for a kind of absolute independence that we think is problematic.

[00:43:08.490] – Grumbine

Is a better term than sovereignty because it denotes more interconnection. There are differences in capacity, and those differences are grounded in power relations. Addressing those power relations as part of the MMT project, broadly conceived in the context of political economy and humanity.

[00:43:29.260] – Ferguson

Dropping sovereignty and adopting other explanatory language and improvising and coming up with different explanatory language to make up for this absence of sovereignty is precisely about rearticulating that problem of power, and I think rearticulating ways that are more realistic and explanatory and potentially more empowering.

[00:43:50.820] – Grumbine

If you’re describing the uni to someone who is new to MMT, is it accurate to say that the University is taking the role of sovereign?

[00:43:59.520] – Ferguson

Yes. To me, we need to send Tick (Richard Rick Segerblom, Clark County Nevada Commissioner who has had discussions with Scott Ferguson) the finance franchise article or one of the million versions of that argument. Right. That money is a legal creation and it has been seized and delegated in certain ways by powerful actors in the private sector.

And if private banks and financial institutions and fintech entrepreneurs can issue credit out of thin air because they have licenses, they are franchisees, then why the hell can’t counties or universities or neighborhood councils or whatever do that, too? Yes. The uni is like a distributed currency issuance regime.

Exactly. And our argument, this is in MMT. This is not reinventing the wheel. Money is a distributed system. Right. It is not just concentrated into one point. And so the question is, how do you organize that distributed system and who is being empowered, and who’s being disenfranchised? I do want to say something else.

I wasn’t able to work into my talk, which is the term sovereignty gets used in other ways and in other ways on the left, broadly speaking, and people who are fighting for justice and for empowerment and for democracy and socialization. So one way is to speak in terms of resource sovereignty, right, like food sovereignty or energy sovereignty.

I prefer not to use that term if I’m going to talk about it. And certainly in the realm of MMT, and I prefer to use what I think is actually being expressed there – terms like food resilience or sustainability. Right. Then the other way that one hears sovereignty used all the time is in various Indigenous communities, Indigenous sovereignty. And to be perfectly frank, I find that is not my place to police their language.

If they want to use sovereignty to describe their pursuit of reclaiming their political dignity and their social production process, I’m not going to criticize them. I think I’m here to stay in my lane. I’m MMT interdisciplinary scholar and organizer and activist, and I’m here to critique this term and its function historically and what it means for this community.

[00:46:32.610] – Grumbine

Some people insist that there can’t be fiat currency without imperialism. They back up this assertion with examples like the petrodollar or even Imperial China. How do you counter the argument that a monetarily sovereign government requires imperialism?

[00:46:49.920] – Ferguson

Right. So different ways and depending on the audience and who I’m talking to, I would take this on in different ways. First thing to say is I just don’t think sovereignty exists. Right. I think it’s a myth. And it’s a poor description of what we call fiat currency. Right. Essentially, it’s government-issued credit, government levied and issued credit. Right.

That’s what MMT is after. And what MMT says is, it’s a description of how money works. Right. And it’s not even a question of can we have it or not have it? We critique the myth of barter. MMTers do not think that money is just exchange of commodities or exchange of services that somehow bubbles up into some systemic macroeconomic pattern. Right.

Let me say this, from a Money on the Left point of view, something like money, something like a system of credit and obligations has existed since the beginning of writing in humanity. And even if we don’t call it money, money is a species of that system of governance and writing. And this gets back to my talk, which is I think that the modern conception of politics as an imposition from the outside predicated on external relations in the state of nature between individuals and smaller groups is just the wrong way to go about it.

I don’t think it works that way. And that’s not to say that there isn’t colonial and imperial violence or that money hasn’t been involved in all kinds of terrible things that we critique. And this isn’t going to be convincing to the person who made this critique to you. But I would say there’s just no getting around macro and meso problems of collective interdependence and obligations and credit.

[00:48:50.830] – Grumbine

Please speak further about community, credit, unions, and what they should look like.

[00:48:56.730] – Ferguson

My collective has written about this and talked about this in many places on our own podcast also Real Progressives and Macro N Cheese. And we did, I think, one of these sessions on it. So forgive me if I’m just rehashing some of that. But so we were talking about taking the public University or public University systems as a model.

They are already massive productive infrastructure, and they are economic anchors for gigantic regions. Often they own the most property in those regions. Often they are one of, if not the biggest, employers in those regions. To a certain extent, it’s mind-blowing. And we confuse all kinds of people and leftists with our idea. But to a certain extent, that’s the easiest.

That’s a super easy model because these are already powerful institutions, institutions that are privatized, institutions that are screwed up in so many ways. And faculty governance has been alienated, and there’s all kinds of problems. But in terms of a credit issuance system, we’re saying these are already economic anchors.

We give private banks the capacity to issue credit in the form of loans that they extend out of thin air to private actors in the community that they think are going to be profitable, right, to serve the profit motive, loans that have to be paid back, and according to a logic of the profit motive. Our argument is there’s no reason why credit issuance has to be driven by loan and then profit and return.

We can extend that credit creation capacity to universities, and there’s different ways of doing that. The most powerful way would be to have a mass movement with many arms that end up pressuring the Federal Reserve, at least in the United States, to essentially create what are called swap lines. And every time the public University system, like the UC system, creates a budget, it then creates a certain amount of uni’s to cover that budget, and then the Fed immediately converts those uni’s into dollars.

Then the University system spends those dollars out into the economy. Now, if the political movement is not there to pressure the Fed, you can create smaller fiscal circuits, which arguably because the University is this economic anchor, it’s really well-positioned to create these circuits and those circuits, those fiscal tax circuits are basically creating credit that is then receivable for anything the University provides.

Now there’s power politics around privatized contracts. Who runs the food service system, who runs the University housing? Is it the University, or has it been contracted out? All that has to be thought out and hammered out. But then there’s all kinds of other intermediate, meso-level stuff, things that could be done, like getting the local municipalities, the county, the city, to receive those unique credits in taxes, like for property taxes, for example, that would extend receivability more.

Local businesses can either voluntarily or by virtue of a local property tax, also be looped into the uni circuit. Schools already have credit unions. Schools already have various kinds of meal cards, and students today have debit cards have all kinds of cards. It would just be about extending that out more. Right. And then the granting part is to say, the terms of issuance are not alone.

They’re not predicated on the quantitative paying back. But that doesn’t mean that there isn’t an obligation. Right. And my colleague and friend Ben Wilson, whose training at UMKC will always use the example of what universities and what faculty do all the time now. We have a grant economy, right. I get a grant from some humanities organization or whatever, and I write a proposal, and I’m like, I’m going to do this research, and I’m going to finish an introduction and chapters one and two of my forthcoming book.

If you give me this grant money to work in the summer, and I can send my kids to camp and I don’t have to teach, and I can just hammer out these chapters, and at the end of them, I promise you, I will send you evidence that these chapters are done in some form or another, and there can be penalties baked into that. So the obligation structure is there.

The credit is there, but I don’t have to pay it back. Right. So one can imagine extending that logic to community and environmental projects. What you have to pay back is not the money. What you have to pay back is the fact that you’ve organized and mobilized your community, do weatherize houses in your community. Right. So that’s sort of what I mean.

People have been about like public banks and postal banking, and that can be part of it, too. I think that we have this tendency to equate money with private exchange, revenue-driven relations, and the profit motive, not just as a function of greed, but as a function of the necessity of money, because money is only this relationship of privation and getting it and losing it and then trying to pay it back.

And I think what MMT and endogenous money approaches open up is the fact that, no, that’s all socially politically constructed and it serves scarcity. It’s a construction of scarcity. We already kind of have all kinds of institutions that work more through granting and then, like, totally to go through the looking glass.

And I think I was kind of doing it in my presentation. I would argue that at bottom, all money issuance is granting so that a loan is a grant with a payback requirement, essentially because you don’t really have any money without it being issued first without it being granted first.

[00:55:11.090] – Grumbine

Well, that was it. Scott Ferguson on RP Live. You can follow Scott on Twitter @videotroph is the troph, and be sure to check out Moneyontheleft.Org where you’ll find all their great podcasts and plenty of other great material. Again, this is Steve Grumbine on Macro N Cheese. I’m out of here.

[00:55:41.280] – Ending Credits

Macro N Cheese is produced by Andy Kennedy, descriptive writing by Virginia Cotts, and promotional artwork by Mindy Donham.  Macro N Cheese is publicly funded by our Real Progressives Patreon account. If you would like to donate to Macro N Cheese, please visit patreon.com/realprogressives

Related Podcast Episodes

Related Articles